Active Stocks
Thu Apr 18 2024 15:59:07
  1. Tata Steel share price
  2. 160.00 -0.03%
  1. Power Grid Corporation Of India share price
  2. 280.20 2.13%
  1. NTPC share price
  2. 351.40 -2.19%
  1. Infosys share price
  2. 1,420.55 0.41%
  1. Wipro share price
  2. 444.30 -0.96%
Business News/ Opinion / The politics and plumbing of reforms
BackBack

The politics and plumbing of reforms

Statecraft is about shaping political constituencies rather than waiting for a favourable consensus to emerge

Photo: Pradeep Gaur/Mint Premium
Photo: Pradeep Gaur/Mint

Finance minister Arun Jaitley recently expressed his government’s intent to pursue a gradualist reform agenda, one predicated on political acceptability. Jaitley’s statement, coupled with the budget’s modest ambition, is consistent with Montek Singh Ahluwalia’s quip that India has a “strong consensus for weak reforms".

The accuracy of this narrative is suspect on two counts: many reform agendas (take financial or infrastructure reforms for instance) are politically non-controversial; and the 2014 election has damaged the weak consensus argument by granting the Narendra Modi government the clearest mandate for reforms in recent memory.

Even where agreement is weak, the government need not wait for robust consensus. In spite of “weak consensus", India witnessed strong reforms for over a decade, starting in 1991, including politically difficult reforms, such as the National Pension System. Those reforms, in part, created the constituencies that helped the Bharatiya Janata Party win the 2014 election on a platform of economic renewal.

The “first generation" reforms of the 1990s marked the first significant shift towards more private sector and trade-oriented policies, with a more limited role for government. India has pocketed most of the productivity pay-offs from these landmark reforms. Today “second generation" reforms—supplying better public goods and correcting market failures—are required to spur higher growth. In some sectors, such as agriculture, even first generation reforms are pending. The failure of United Progressive Alliance’s (UPA’s) “Dream Team" to enact these reforms was puzzling, especially given its stronger electoral mandate in 2009. So why did it fail?

In a 2012 speech, Raghuram Rajan blamed the nexus between the “connected" and the “political elites", arguing that reforms would have dried up the well of patronage that many drank from. While this hypothesis has obvious merit, it is too simplistic.

First, this nexus, if it existed, failed to prevent many actions that hurt the “connected", such as the mess around general anti-avoidance tax rules. Second, India’s most powerful corporate entities invested heavily in infrastructure in the last decade, but failed to resolve the lack of decision-making on stalled projects. Other reforms which would have helped the connected, such as labour market liberalization, never materialized. Furthermore, the UPA government passed initiatives adverse to such a nexus, such as the Right to Information (RTI) Act.

A second narrative is that the UPA was indecisive. Yet, its leadership was ruthlessly decisive in legislating its sweeping social policy agenda, which included rights to food, education, and employment, and a new land acquisition Bill.

The UPA’s intellectual bankruptcy on public sector reforms comprises a third narrative. But the UPA actually displayed considerable intellectual initiative. For example, P. Chidambaram personally oversaw drafting of the Direct Taxes Code Bill. Similar stories can be told about the Goods and Services Tax (GST) and administrative, welfare, and financial sector reforms.

A final narrative is that the public does not support reforms. According to Pew, since 2007, the percentage of respondents in India completely or mostly agreeing with the statement “Most people are better off in a free market economy, even though some people are rich and some are poor" has ranged between 61 and 81.

So what explains the UPA’s failure on reforms, and how might the National Democratic Alliance (NDA) government learn from it?

The UPA, divided at the top between Sonia Gandhi and Manmohan Singh, advanced the priorities of the former over the latter. Thus, the welfare agenda promoted by the National Advisory Council was feverishly implemented, while the reform agenda, where ministers or government commissions had led the thinking languished. When UPA was re-elected in 2009 on the back of sustained high growth and welfare expansion, it read its mandate as being fundamentally about the latter.

There should be no doubt about Modi’s mandate: exit polls confirm this election was about “the economy, stupid". But since political capital is finite, the NDA must use it for tough second generation reforms befitting this political window and aspirational mandate.

Second, where UPA pursued reforms, it was politically clumsy. On GST and Aadhaar, it invested in their intellectual development, but was ham-handed in the political follow-on. It failed to create constituencies of support, was opaque in its deliberations, and lacked an effective communications strategy.

On controversial reforms, the NDA needs to muster the risk-taking appetite and political skills it demonstrated on the campaign to generate a pro-reform movement. Statecraft is about shaping political constituencies rather than waiting for a favourable consensus to emerge. Many good ideas are simply awaiting political impetus for implementation.

Third, UPA had a penchant for centralized planning, which stifled state-level initiative. Indian federalism can serve as a laboratory for reform experimentation, but only when the centre creates a hospitable environment.

Many reforms may be more easily attainable working through state capitals rather than Delhi; we should see more state experimentation such as Rajasthan’s proposed labour reforms. Modi is exceptionally placed to craft a new federal bargain as he innately sees issues through the prism of states.

Finally, even on areas it gave top billing, UPA ignored state capacity. A report on RTI demonstrates that the demand for information far outstrips the state’s ability to cope. Legislating food security before fixing the public distribution system prioritized announcement over implementation. One can debate whether UPA’s electoral performance would have improved had it translated outlays into outcomes, but the failure to do so surely hurt its chances.

Quick fixes are politically expedient but their positive outcomes are fleeting. As Pratap Bhanu Mehta wrote recently, “maximum governance" does not automatically follow from “minimum government". Previous governments have penned innumerable blueprints for second generation reforms, but they lacked the political will, skills or capital to succeed. Reform initiatives that were pursued often failed due to inadequate attention to state capacity. This government has a once-in-a-generation opportunity to translate ideas into institutional change.

Suyash Rai is a senior consultant at the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy in
New Delhi.

Milan Vaishnav is an associate with the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace in Washington, D.C.

Comments are welcome at theirview@livemint.com

Follow Mint Opinion on Twitter at https://twitter.com/Mint_Opinion

Unlock a world of Benefits! From insightful newsletters to real-time stock tracking, breaking news and a personalized newsfeed – it's all here, just a click away! Login Now!

Catch all the Business News, Market News, Breaking News Events and Latest News Updates on Live Mint. Download The Mint News App to get Daily Market Updates.
More Less
Published: 28 Jul 2014, 06:06 PM IST
Next Story footLogo
Recommended For You
Switch to the Mint app for fast and personalized news - Get App